WEBVTT 00:00:09.566 --> 00:00:11.490 - [Alex] In our last video, 00:00:11.490 --> 00:00:14.490 Don Boudreaux used the simple example of Bob and Anne 00:00:14.490 --> 00:00:15.920 to demonstrate comparative advantage. 00:00:15.920 --> 00:00:18.920 In the next two videos, 00:00:18.920 --> 00:00:19.920 we'll dive deeper into comparative advantage 00:00:19.920 --> 00:00:22.280 and give you a homework question 00:00:22.280 --> 00:00:25.532 to test how well you're doing in understanding the concept. 00:00:26.675 --> 00:00:29.675 Let's get going. 00:00:30.092 --> 00:00:34.070 Comparative advantage is the theory of trade. 00:00:34.250 --> 00:00:37.240 It explains why people trade, and which good people should trade 00:00:37.240 --> 00:00:40.240 if they want to maximize their well being. 00:00:40.240 --> 00:00:44.520 It's actually useful to understand comparative advantage 00:00:44.700 --> 00:00:46.470 to begin with a false theory, 00:00:46.470 --> 00:00:49.470 a very plausible but incorrect theory of trade -- 00:00:49.470 --> 00:00:51.080 namely the theory of absolute advantage. 00:00:51.080 --> 00:00:54.080 So let's consider a simple model. 00:00:54.080 --> 00:00:58.180 Let's suppose that labor is the only good used in production 00:00:58.360 --> 00:01:01.569 and that we can produce computers or shirts. 00:01:01.569 --> 00:01:04.569 Let's suppose that in Mexico it takes 12 units of labor 00:01:04.569 --> 00:01:07.905 to produce one computer. 00:01:07.905 --> 00:01:08.980 Again, in Mexico, 00:01:08.980 --> 00:01:11.980 it takes two units of labor to produce one shirt. 00:01:11.980 --> 00:01:12.980 Now let's compare it with the United States. 00:01:12.980 --> 00:01:15.460 To make it simple, we'll suppose in the United States 00:01:15.460 --> 00:01:20.470 it takes just one unit of labor to make one computer, 00:01:20.650 --> 00:01:24.790 and one unit of labor to create one shirt. 00:01:24.790 --> 00:01:27.790 Now, from the absolute advantage theory of trade it should -- 00:01:27.790 --> 00:01:30.010 it may seem obvious that there in fact will -- 00:01:30.010 --> 00:01:33.010 be no trade here. 00:01:33.010 --> 00:01:38.660 It may seem obvious that the United States 00:01:38.840 --> 00:01:41.340 will outcompete Mexico on all margins. 00:01:41.340 --> 00:01:44.340 After all, the United States in this example 00:01:44.340 --> 00:01:45.530 is much more productive at producing computers 00:01:45.530 --> 00:01:48.530 and also more productive at producing shirts than Mexico. 00:01:48.530 --> 00:01:50.270 So this is a case where we might think, 00:01:50.270 --> 00:01:53.270 with the United States so much better 00:01:53.270 --> 00:01:55.660 at producing both computers and shirts, 00:01:55.660 --> 00:01:58.660 that certainly there's no reason 00:01:58.660 --> 00:02:03.470 for the United States to trade with Mexico, 00:02:03.470 --> 00:02:06.470 its less productive neighbor. 00:02:06.470 --> 00:02:08.950 That's the theory of absolute advantage. 00:02:08.950 --> 00:02:11.950 It's very plausible; it's also very wrong. 00:02:11.950 --> 00:02:15.780 To see why it's wrong, let's take another simple example. 00:02:15.960 --> 00:02:18.580 Here's a picture of Martha Stewart ironing her shirt. 00:02:18.580 --> 00:02:21.580 Now, let's stipulate that Martha Stewart 00:02:21.580 --> 00:02:23.480 has an absolute advantage in ironing. 00:02:23.480 --> 00:02:26.480 She has an advantage in ironing just like the United States 00:02:26.480 --> 00:02:30.340 had an advantage in producing computers and shirts 00:02:30.520 --> 00:02:31.520 in the previous example. 00:02:31.520 --> 00:02:33.657 In other words, we'll stipulate that Martha Stewart 00:02:33.657 --> 00:02:38.705 can iron a shirt better and in less time than anyone else. 00:02:38.800 --> 00:02:43.186 So if Martha Stewart has an absolute advantage in ironing 00:02:43.200 --> 00:02:47.190 should Martha Stewart iron her own shirts? 00:02:47.190 --> 00:02:50.190 Of course the answer here is, no. 00:02:50.190 --> 00:02:53.290 Why not? 00:02:53.290 --> 00:02:56.290 Well, every hour which Martha Stewart spends 00:02:56.290 --> 00:02:58.590 ironing her shirts is an hour she's not spending 00:02:58.590 --> 00:03:01.590 doing something else which is even more valuable, 00:03:01.590 --> 00:03:03.710 running her own business for example -- 00:03:03.710 --> 00:03:06.710 running her billion-dollar business. 00:03:06.710 --> 00:03:08.700 And in fact in a famous statement, Martha Stewart -- 00:03:08.700 --> 00:03:11.700 because she's very wise -- 00:03:11.700 --> 00:03:13.670 she said, "I don't always do all of my own ironing, 00:03:13.670 --> 00:03:16.670 even though I wish that I could." 00:03:16.670 --> 00:03:21.120 Let's take a little bit more detail about why it doesn't make sense 00:03:21.300 --> 00:03:24.370 for Martha Stewart to iron her own shirts. 00:03:24.370 --> 00:03:27.370 The most important point to remember 00:03:27.370 --> 00:03:29.650 is that the important cause is opportunity cost. 00:03:29.650 --> 00:03:32.650 So what is the opportunity cost to Martha Stewart 00:03:32.650 --> 00:03:34.510 of spending an hour ironing her own shirts? 00:03:34.510 --> 00:03:37.510 Well, it could be thousands of dollars, at least. 00:03:37.510 --> 00:03:43.700 Martha Stewart would be better off 00:03:43.880 --> 00:03:45.760 if she specializes in producing her television show, 00:03:45.760 --> 00:03:46.760 and then she trades with someone else 00:03:46.760 --> 00:03:48.760 who has a lower opportunity cost of ironing. 00:03:48.760 --> 00:03:51.540 It doesn't make sense for Martha Stewart 00:03:51.540 --> 00:03:54.540 to iron her own shirts because the cost of her doing so 00:03:56.380 --> 00:03:59.380 is devoting her time to something where she's even more valuable 00:03:59.380 --> 00:04:02.180 or she's even better, 00:04:02.180 --> 00:04:05.180 and that is producing her own television show. 00:04:05.180 --> 00:04:08.230 So Martha Stewart has a comparative advantage 00:04:08.230 --> 00:04:11.230 in running her business, or to put it slightly differently 00:04:11.230 --> 00:04:15.910 she has a comparative disadvantage in ironing. 00:04:16.089 --> 00:04:21.810 The cost to her of ironing is very high 00:04:21.990 --> 00:04:28.970 precisely because she is so much more productive at other tasks. 00:04:29.150 --> 00:04:32.020 So Martha Stewart wants to specialize in what she is best at, 00:04:32.020 --> 00:04:35.020 in where she has a comparative advantage. 00:04:35.020 --> 00:04:37.770 Other people are almost as good as her at ironing clothes, 00:04:37.770 --> 00:04:40.770 but they're not as good as her at producing their own TV show. 00:04:40.770 --> 00:04:44.466 So that's why Martha Stewart shouldn't iron her own shirts. 00:04:46.600 --> 00:04:48.840 Let's go back now to our previous example 00:04:48.840 --> 00:04:51.840 of the United States and Mexico. 00:04:51.840 --> 00:04:55.870 So the key to comparative advantage is understanding opportunity cost. 00:04:56.050 --> 00:05:00.810 So let's take this previous figure we had from a previous slide 00:05:00.990 --> 00:05:03.460 and turn it into an opportunity cost figure. 00:05:03.460 --> 00:05:06.460 So remember what this top figure tells us -- 00:05:06.460 --> 00:05:08.390 it tells us for example that in Mexico 00:05:08.390 --> 00:05:11.390 it takes 12 units of labor to produce one computer, 00:05:11.390 --> 00:05:13.410 and in Mexico it takes two units of labor 00:05:13.410 --> 00:05:16.410 to produce one shirt and so forth. 00:05:16.410 --> 00:05:19.220 Okay, for the United States, it just takes one unit of labor 00:05:19.220 --> 00:05:21.085 to produce either a computer or a shirt. 00:05:21.400 --> 00:05:27.460 Okay, now let's begin with an easy case. 00:05:27.640 --> 00:05:34.080 What's the opportunity cost of one computer in the United States? 00:05:34.260 --> 00:05:35.960 In other words, to produce an additional computer 00:05:35.960 --> 00:05:38.960 in the United States, what would we have to give up? 00:05:38.960 --> 00:05:40.250 Well, in order to get that additional computer, 00:05:40.250 --> 00:05:43.250 we'd have to take labor from shirt production 00:05:43.250 --> 00:05:44.940 and move it into computer production. 00:05:44.940 --> 00:05:47.940 In particular, we have to take one unit of labor 00:05:47.940 --> 00:05:53.280 from shirt production and move it into computer production. 00:05:53.460 --> 00:05:58.970 That would get us one more computer at the cost of one shirt. 00:05:59.150 --> 00:06:01.570 So the opportunity cost 00:06:01.570 --> 00:06:02.570 of one computer in the United States is one shirt. 00:06:02.570 --> 00:06:04.570 What is the opportunity cost of a shirt? 00:06:04.570 --> 00:06:08.250 Well, the opportunity cost of a shirt, 00:06:08.430 --> 00:06:12.820 what you're giving up to produce an extra shirt, 00:06:12.820 --> 00:06:13.820 is one computer. 00:06:13.820 --> 00:06:15.820 Okay, slightly harder case -- 00:06:15.820 --> 00:06:20.210 what's the opportunity cost of one computer in Mexico? 00:06:20.210 --> 00:06:23.210 So in Mexico, in order to get an additional computer, 00:06:23.210 --> 00:06:25.390 you'd have to transfer labor 00:06:25.390 --> 00:06:28.390 from shirt production into computer production. 00:06:28.390 --> 00:06:32.160 But how many units of labor do you need to transfer? 00:06:32.340 --> 00:06:34.450 You need to transfer 12 units of labor 00:06:34.450 --> 00:06:35.450 in order to get one computer. 00:06:35.450 --> 00:06:37.450 You're going to have to take 12 units of labor 00:06:37.450 --> 00:06:40.010 from shirt production. 00:06:40.010 --> 00:06:43.010 That means how many fewer shirts? 00:06:43.010 --> 00:06:45.340 Since it takes two units of labor to produce one shirt, 00:06:45.340 --> 00:06:48.340 and you've got to move 12 units of labor. 00:06:48.340 --> 00:06:53.820 It means that the opportunity cost of one computer is six shirts. 00:06:54.000 --> 00:06:57.120 If you need an additional computer, 00:06:57.120 --> 00:06:58.120 it's going to cost you six fewer shirts 00:06:58.120 --> 00:07:00.120 in order to get that computer. 00:07:00.120 --> 00:07:03.700 Going the other way, in order to get an additional shirt, 00:07:03.880 --> 00:07:07.450 you're going to have to give up one-sixth of a computer. 00:07:07.450 --> 00:07:10.450 Okay, so now we have our opportunity cost, 00:07:10.450 --> 00:07:12.150 and now it's actually pretty simple 00:07:12.150 --> 00:07:15.150 because what the theory of comparative advantage says 00:07:15.150 --> 00:07:18.170 is that you should produce, or you can produce at lowest cost. 00:07:18.170 --> 00:07:21.170 So who here has the lowest cost of producing a computer? 00:07:21.170 --> 00:07:28.230 The lowest cost of producing a computer 00:07:28.410 --> 00:07:29.940 is the United States. 00:07:29.940 --> 00:07:32.940 The United States is the low opportunity cost producer 00:07:32.940 --> 00:07:40.050 of computers. 00:07:40.050 --> 00:07:41.050 Now, who is the low cost producer of shirts? 00:07:41.050 --> 00:07:43.050 Well, it's Mexico. 00:07:43.050 --> 00:07:45.160 In Mexico, you're only giving up one-sixth of a computer 00:07:45.160 --> 00:07:48.160 to produce a shirt. 00:07:48.160 --> 00:07:49.160 In the United States, you're giving up one computer 00:07:49.160 --> 00:07:51.900 to produce a shirt. 00:07:51.900 --> 00:07:56.230 So you'd much rather produce shirts in Mexico 00:07:56.230 --> 00:07:59.230 where the opportunity cost is lower. 00:07:59.230 --> 00:08:02.650 Okay, what we're learning here 00:08:02.650 --> 00:08:05.650 is that Mexico ought to specialize in computers 00:08:05.650 --> 00:08:07.710 because they're the low cost producer of -- 00:08:07.710 --> 00:08:10.710 excuse me, in shirts 00:08:10.710 --> 00:08:11.710 because they're the low cost producer of shirts. 00:08:11.710 --> 00:08:14.430 The United States ought to specialize more towards computers 00:08:14.430 --> 00:08:19.810 because they're the low cost producer of computers. 00:08:19.990 --> 00:08:21.380 Let's look in more detail. 00:08:21.380 --> 00:08:24.380 So I'm going to leave some of the details to you actually 00:08:24.380 --> 00:08:25.380 and some homework questions 00:08:25.380 --> 00:08:28.360 which we'll go over in the future video. 00:08:28.360 --> 00:08:32.250 So question one -- let's suppose in Mexico and in the United States 00:08:32.429 --> 00:08:35.230 each have 24 units of labor, 00:08:35.230 --> 00:08:36.230 and that each devote 12 units of labor 00:08:36.230 --> 00:08:38.230 to producing computers 00:08:38.230 --> 00:08:40.419 and 12 units of labor to producing shirts. 00:08:40.419 --> 00:08:43.419 That will be our baseline scenario. 00:08:43.419 --> 00:08:47.228 The question is -- "What is total world production in this scenario?" 00:08:47.228 --> 00:08:48.802 That's question one. 00:08:48.802 --> 00:08:54.590 Question two -- suppose that Mexico specializes in producing 00:08:54.770 --> 00:08:56.380 what it produces at lowest opportunity cost -- 00:08:56.380 --> 00:08:59.380 we just saw that was shirts -- 00:08:59.380 --> 00:09:02.200 and suppose that the U.S. transfers two units of labor 00:09:02.200 --> 00:09:05.200 from shirts to producing what it produces 00:09:05.200 --> 00:09:09.030 at lowest opportunity cost -- that's computers. 00:09:09.030 --> 00:09:12.030 What then is total world production? 00:09:12.030 --> 00:09:16.860 Finally, can trade make both countries better off? 00:09:17.040 --> 00:09:19.760 Here what I'd like you to do is give a concrete example 00:09:19.760 --> 00:09:22.760 of how many units have to be traded from where to where 00:09:22.760 --> 00:09:24.530 in order to make both countries better off, 00:09:24.530 --> 00:09:27.530 if that in fact is possible. 00:09:27.530 --> 00:09:28.790 So to help you along a little bit -- 00:09:28.790 --> 00:09:31.790 I know that was a mouthful -- 00:09:31.790 --> 00:09:34.680 Let's take a look at this in terms of a diagram. 00:09:34.680 --> 00:09:37.680 To help you along, I want you to fill in these tables. 00:09:37.680 --> 00:09:39.700 So our basic table 00:09:39.700 --> 00:09:42.700 from which you're going to draw the information is up here. 00:09:42.700 --> 00:09:44.270 If both countries have 24 units of labor, 00:09:44.270 --> 00:09:47.270 half devoted to computers, half to shirts, 00:09:47.270 --> 00:09:49.400 there's no trade, 00:09:49.400 --> 00:09:52.400 so production is equal to consumption 00:09:52.400 --> 00:09:53.940 in this first example -- what is production going to be? 00:09:54.120 --> 00:09:57.990 So Mexico, 12 units of labor with computers, 12 shirts. 00:09:58.170 --> 00:09:59.170 How many computers, how many shirts? 00:09:59.170 --> 00:10:00.440 Same for the United States. 00:10:00.440 --> 00:10:02.000 How many computers? How many shirts? 00:10:02.000 --> 00:10:05.000 What's total world production? 00:10:05.000 --> 00:10:06.100 Then suppose we have specialization -- 00:10:06.100 --> 00:10:09.100 what's production is going to be? 00:10:09.100 --> 00:10:14.430 So Mexico has zero units of labor in computers, 24 in shirts. 00:10:14.610 --> 00:10:19.200 United States has 14 units of labor in computers, 10 in shirts. 00:10:19.380 --> 00:10:22.190 What's production in each case? 00:10:22.190 --> 00:10:23.190 What is the total for the world? 00:10:23.190 --> 00:10:25.913 Then finally, can we -- 00:10:25.913 --> 00:10:28.636 with production, with specialization, 00:10:28.636 --> 00:10:29.636 can we now find a way to have trade 00:10:29.636 --> 00:10:31.540 which makes both countries better off? 00:10:31.540 --> 00:10:32.940 What's the exact, or what's a exact price ratio 00:10:32.940 --> 00:10:35.940 at which that trade will occur? 00:10:35.940 --> 00:10:37.550 We'll take that up in a later video. 00:10:37.550 --> 00:10:40.550 Let me just finally give you some concluding comments 00:10:40.550 --> 00:10:42.353 on comparative advantage. 00:10:43.400 --> 00:10:44.400 I want to conclude with a caution 00:10:44.400 --> 00:10:47.080 but also a big picture view of comparative advantage. 00:10:47.080 --> 00:10:50.950 In the two country/person examples I've been working with 00:10:51.130 --> 00:10:53.420 in order to explain the theory, 00:10:53.420 --> 00:10:56.420 everyone is made better off by trade. 00:10:56.420 --> 00:10:57.900 In larger examples, trade will increase aggregate wealth, 00:10:57.900 --> 00:11:00.900 but some individuals can be made worse off. 00:11:00.900 --> 00:11:03.450 And that should make perfect sense. 00:11:03.450 --> 00:11:06.450 After all, if A and B have been trading, 00:11:06.450 --> 00:11:08.080 and then because tariffs fall 00:11:08.080 --> 00:11:11.080 or because transportation costs fall, 00:11:11.080 --> 00:11:13.310 if A starts trading with C, then B may be worse off, 00:11:13.310 --> 00:11:16.310 even though A, B and C together have greater aggregate wealth. 00:11:16.310 --> 00:11:19.990 That's just a caution to keep in mind. 00:11:20.170 --> 00:11:21.810 Now here's the big picture. 00:11:21.810 --> 00:11:24.810 Comparative advantage -- it applies to people, 00:11:24.810 --> 00:11:26.910 to groups, to countries. 00:11:26.910 --> 00:11:29.910 It's sometimes called the law of association. 00:11:29.910 --> 00:11:31.576 And it's not only a beautiful theory -- 00:11:31.576 --> 00:11:33.243 it's a very positive and optimistic theory 00:11:33.243 --> 00:11:34.910 because it says that we all have something to gain from trade. 00:11:34.910 --> 00:11:41.010 It says by working together, we can increase total wealth. 00:11:41.190 --> 00:11:47.460 Moreover we can -- I like to phrase this in terms 00:11:47.640 --> 00:11:49.870 of a politically correct slogan: "Diversity is strength." 00:11:49.870 --> 00:11:52.870 You've probably heard that slogan before. 00:11:52.870 --> 00:11:58.230 What comparative advantage adds to this 00:11:58.410 --> 00:12:01.360 is that diversity and strength when combined with trade -- 00:12:01.360 --> 00:12:04.360 it's trade which turns diversity into strength. 00:12:04.360 --> 00:12:06.882 That's really the bottom line on comparative advantage. 00:12:06.882 --> 00:12:08.629 We'll be saying more in future videos. 00:12:08.629 --> 00:12:11.629 Thanks. 00:12:11.629 --> 00:12:12.629 - [Narrator] If you want to test yourself, 00:12:12.629 --> 00:12:15.022 click "Practice Questions." 00:12:15.022 --> 00:12:18.361 Or, if you're ready to move on, just click "Next Video."