Return to Video

25. Contracts: Public Policy

  • 0:00 - 0:02
    >> In some circumstances,
  • 0:02 - 0:04
    a court will refuse to
    enforce a contract on
  • 0:04 - 0:08
    the grounds that to do so
    is against public policy.
  • 0:08 - 0:11
    To give an extreme example,
  • 0:11 - 0:13
    based on an actual case from Japan,
  • 0:13 - 0:17
    a woman hired a hitman to murder
    her husband and his mistress.
  • 0:17 - 0:21
    The hitman botched the job
    and failed to kill either,
  • 0:21 - 0:25
    and the woman sued him
    for breach of contract.
  • 0:25 - 0:29
    Despite the existence of mutual
    assent and consideration,
  • 0:29 - 0:30
    the court dismissed her case,
  • 0:30 - 0:33
    refusing to enforce the contract.
  • 0:33 - 0:35
    Given that murder is a crime,
  • 0:35 - 0:39
    it is not hard to see that a
    contract for murder, that is,
  • 0:39 - 0:41
    a contract to commit a crime,
  • 0:41 - 0:44
    is a contract against public policy.
  • 0:44 - 0:48
    But the problem with refusing
    to enforce a contract on
  • 0:48 - 0:51
    the grounds that it is
    against public policy is that
  • 0:51 - 0:55
    the concept of public
    policy is very malleable
  • 0:55 - 1:00
    and has a tendency to become tinged
    with a judge's views on morality.
  • 1:00 - 1:05
    For instance, in jurisdictions where
    prostitution and gambling are crimes,
  • 1:05 - 1:09
    courts have refused to enforce
    contracts involving these activities,
  • 1:09 - 1:12
    such as promises to pay gambling debts.
  • 1:12 - 1:16
    Such cases are analogous
    to the hitman contract.
  • 1:16 - 1:20
    Courts refuse to enforce contracts
    involving criminal activity.
  • 1:20 - 1:23
    But some courts have
    also refused to enforce
  • 1:23 - 1:28
    gambling debts in jurisdictions
    where gambling is not a crime.
  • 1:28 - 1:32
    Those courts have reason that
    although gambling may not be illegal,
  • 1:32 - 1:35
    it is nevertheless immoral behavior.
  • 1:35 - 1:38
    Section 178, subsection 1,
  • 1:38 - 1:41
    of the second restatement
    states that a promise is
  • 1:41 - 1:46
    unenforceable on the grounds of
    public policy in two instances.
  • 1:46 - 1:49
    First, where specific legislation
  • 1:49 - 1:52
    renders certain kinds of
    promises unenforceable.
  • 1:52 - 1:56
    Second, where the interest in
    enforcement of the promise,
  • 1:56 - 1:59
    such as the party's expectations,
  • 1:59 - 2:01
    is clearly outweighed by a public policy
  • 2:01 - 2:06
    against enforcement of those kinds
    of promises such as gambling.
  • 2:06 - 2:09
    The section goes on to identify
    some relevant factors.
  • 2:09 - 2:13
    But because the factors
    are themselves vague and
  • 2:13 - 2:16
    because different courts assign
    different weights to different factors,
  • 2:16 - 2:21
    it is difficult to predict the
    outcome in any given case.
  • 2:21 - 2:23
    Your text gives two other examples of
  • 2:23 - 2:28
    contractual relationships that may be
    challenged as against public policy;
  • 2:28 - 2:34
    covenants to not compete against a former
    employer and surrogacy agreements.
  • 2:34 - 2:36
    An interesting line of cases examine
  • 2:36 - 2:39
    the issue whether it is
    against public policy for
  • 2:39 - 2:41
    one party to release the other from
  • 2:41 - 2:45
    any liability arising out
    of the other's negligence.
  • 2:45 - 2:47
    Such releases are fairly common.
  • 2:47 - 2:49
    Many entities that provide
  • 2:49 - 2:53
    recreational activities such as
    horseback riding or scuba diving,
  • 2:53 - 2:57
    routinely require their
    patrons to sign such releases.
  • 2:57 - 3:00
    In deciding whether to
    uphold such releases,
  • 3:00 - 3:04
    courts have not adopted
    many bright line rules.
  • 3:04 - 3:08
    However, one well accepted
    rule is that a party cannot
  • 3:08 - 3:13
    contractually disclaim liability
    for its own gross negligence.
  • 3:13 - 3:16
    But when ordinary negligence is involved,
  • 3:16 - 3:19
    courts have not established
    the bright line rules.
  • 3:19 - 3:24
    Instead, they employ a
    multi-factor balancing test.
  • 3:24 - 3:28
    Economics often plays a role
    in this balancing test.
  • 3:28 - 3:31
    For example, back when cameras required
  • 3:31 - 3:34
    film and film was relatively inexpensive,
  • 3:34 - 3:37
    the manufacturers of
    film regularly limited
  • 3:37 - 3:42
    their liability for defective film
    to the cost of the film itself.
  • 3:42 - 3:45
    Purchasers of defective film
    would sometimes challenge
  • 3:45 - 3:49
    such limitations on the ground that
    they were against public policy.
  • 3:49 - 3:52
    The purchasers would argue that
  • 3:52 - 3:55
    their losses far exceeded
    the cost of the film.
  • 3:55 - 3:59
    In one case, a wedding
    photographer's film was defective,
  • 3:59 - 4:01
    and the plaintiff alleged that it costs
  • 4:01 - 4:05
    several thousand dollars to restage the
    wedding to have the pictures taken.
  • 4:05 - 4:10
    Moreover, purchasers would argue
    that the defective film was
  • 4:10 - 4:13
    the manufacturer's fault
    and public policy should
  • 4:13 - 4:17
    hold negligent parties accountable
    for the losses they cause.
  • 4:17 - 4:22
    The contractual disclaimer of
    liability violated public policy.
  • 4:22 - 4:26
    Nevertheless, in the cases involving film,
  • 4:26 - 4:30
    courts pretty regularly upheld
    contractual disclaimers of liability.
  • 4:30 - 4:34
    The courts reason that the manufacturer's
    risk of being held accountable for
  • 4:34 - 4:36
    large losses would result in
  • 4:36 - 4:40
    a steep increase in the price of
    film for the rest of all of us.
  • 4:40 - 4:42
    As the manufacturers
    would pass on the cost of
  • 4:42 - 4:45
    insuring against such
    losses to their customers,
  • 4:45 - 4:51
    and that on balance this would not
    be beneficial to society as a whole.
  • 4:51 - 4:54
    But this balancing act
    gets more problematic when
  • 4:54 - 4:58
    personal injury as opposed to
    just economic loss is involved.
  • 4:58 - 5:02
    Let's say the cost of a recreational
    activity is fairly modest,
  • 5:02 - 5:05
    say, $40 an hour to go horseback riding.
  • 5:05 - 5:10
    But risks are unavoidable and
    regularly occur because horses are
  • 5:10 - 5:15
    regularly frightened by an unexpected
    noise and they may react by rearing.
  • 5:15 - 5:18
    Moreover, there is a risk of
  • 5:18 - 5:23
    a catastrophic injury such as a
    spinal or brain injury from a fall.
  • 5:23 - 5:28
    In such cases, should the provider
    of the activity be allowed to
  • 5:28 - 5:34
    bargain for a release of liability
    even if the provider is negligent?
  • 5:34 - 5:37
    Courts will have to weigh the extent of
  • 5:37 - 5:40
    injury against the cost of
    insuring against that injury,
  • 5:40 - 5:43
    while factoring in the
    social utility of having
  • 5:43 - 5:47
    such recreational activities
    available at a modest price.
  • 5:47 - 5:50
    It is very difficult to predict
    what a court would conclude.
  • 5:50 - 5:53
    To enforce a release of liability puts
  • 5:53 - 5:56
    the whole economic loss
    on the injured party.
  • 5:56 - 6:00
    But to refuse to enforce the
    release increases the cost of
  • 6:00 - 6:05
    the activity and may result in decreased
    availability of that activity.
  • 6:05 - 6:08
    Conversely, to enforce the release
  • 6:08 - 6:10
    absolves a negligent
    party of responsibility,
  • 6:10 - 6:14
    which may decrease the incentive
    of other horse stables to
  • 6:14 - 6:19
    avoid future negligence and lead
    to a greater number of injuries.
Title:
25. Contracts: Public Policy
Description:

more » « less
Video Language:
English
Duration:
06:19

English subtitles

Revisions